Wednesday, April 8, 2015

On secular stagnation: Larry Summers responds to Ben Bernanke - Lawrence Summers | April 1, 2015

On secular stagnation: Larry Summers responds to Ben Bernanke


Larry Summers has responded to Ben Bernanke's post about secular stagnation:
Ben Bernanke has inaugurated his blog with a set of thoughtful observations on the determinants of real interest rates (see his post here) and the secular stagnation hypothesis that I have invoked in an effort to understand recent macroeconomic developments. I agree with much of what Ben writes and would highlight in particular his recognition that the Fed is in a sense a follower rather than a leader with respect to real interest rates - since they are determined by broad factors bearing on the supply and demand for capital - and his recognition that equilibrium real rates appear to have been trending downward for quite some time. His challenges to the secular stagnation hypothesis have helped me clarify my thinking and provide an opportunity to address a number of points where I think there has been some confusion in the public debate.

Is Secular Stagnation all about the Zero Lower Bound on Nominal Interest Rates?

The essence of secular stagnation is a chronic excess of saving over investment. The natural question for an economist to ask is how can such a chronic excess exist in flexible markets? In particular, shouldn’t interest rates adjust to equate saving and investment at full employment? The most obvious answer is that short term interest rates can’t fall below zero (or some bound close to zero) and this inhibits full adjustment. Ben is skeptical of the importance of this factor, noting that with a 2 percent inflation target real interest rates can fall to -2 percent. True enough. But, it is at least an open question whether central banks can always be credible in claiming they will hit their inflation targets. Market measures of expected inflation suggest that throughout the industrial world inflation may well fall short of 2 percent for a decade or more.
Separately, it is worth noting that there may be other reasons why interest rate adjustment to equate saving and investment at full employment does not operate smoothly. In situations where target saving is important, reductions in rates may increase rather than decrease saving, exacerbating imbalances. Further, there are reasons for concern that protracted very low rates precipitate financial instability by increasing capitalization ratios, raising the duration of assets, encouraging risk taking to chase yield and reducing the financial discipline associated with loan coupon payments.

Do Real Rates below Zero Make Economic Sense?

Ben suggests not-- citing my uncle Paul Samuelson’s famous observation that at a permanently zero or subzero real interest rate it would make sense to invest any amount to level a hill for the resulting saving in transportation costs. Ben grudgingly acknowledges that there are many theoretical mechanisms that could give rise to zero rates. To name a few: credit markets do not work perfectly, property rights are not secure over infinite horizons, property taxes that are explicit or implicit, liquidity service yields on debt, and investors with finite horizons.
To use a phrase Ben has popularized in a different context, negative real rates are phenomenon that we observe in practice if not always in theory. The paper by Hamilton, Harris, Hatzius, and West that he cites demonstrates that during the twentieth century, rates in America have been negative at least 30 percent of the time. In Germany right now, the 10-year nominal rate is 18 basis points suggesting a negative real rate, and the rate is around 60 basis points for 30 years! In Britain, yields on 50-year indexed bonds have been negative for long periods of time.

Were Bubbles an important Contributor to Previous Recoveries?

In support of the idea that the economy suffered from a chronic excess of saving, I have argued that the 2003-2007 recovery and quite possibly the late stages of the 1990s recovery were powered in significant part unsustainable financial conditions. Ben is skeptical, relying on the work of Hamilton et. al (2015) to note that the positive effects of the housing bubble during the previous expansion were offset by an increase in the US trade deficit, and that bubbles were only modestly relevant in the late 1990s. This issue requires much more study. I think that it will be hard to escape the conclusion that household debt grew at an unsustainable pace in the decade before the great financial crisis and that this was an important spur to growth. And I am fairly confident that wealth effects associated with a booming stock market were important in the late 1990s. As I discuss below, I agree with Ben that the open economy aspects are very important and that excess saving in substantial part has emanated from abroad. I have always listed reserve accumulation and foreign demand for safe assets among the major factors acting to depress real interest rates.

How good a solution is expansionary fiscal policy?

Ben accepts the logic of my argument that if reducing rates to equate saving and investment at full employment is infeasible or likely to lead to financial instability, fiscal policy in general and public investment in particular is a natural instrument to promote growth. But he expresses the concern that permanently expansionary fiscal policy may not be possible, given that the government cannot indefinitely expand its debt. This issue is worth further theoretical exploration, but I think Ben greatly understates the scope for feasible fiscal policy for reasons that Brad Delong and I have considered in our 2012 BPEA paper.
Imagine a secular stagnation world with a zero real interest rate. Then, government debt service is very cheap.  As long as a public investment project yields any positive return it will generate enough revenue to service the associated debt. This effect will be magnified if there are any Keynesian fiscal stimulus effects of the project or if there are any hysteresis effects. Notice that with sufficiently low real interest rates, even fiscal stimulus, which does not have supply effects, can pay for itself through mulitiplier effects.
This is not just a theoretical point. The October 2014 IMF World Economic Outlook suggests that public investments in countries where interest rates are near the zero lower bound are likely to significantly reduce debt-to-gdp ratios.
The case for expansionary fiscal policy in economies with very low real interest rates is of course magnified if there are reasons to doubt that the central bank can act on its own to raise inflation expectations. It may well be that in situations where the interest rates are trapped near zero – such as those prevailing in Japan and Germany – expansionary fiscal policy reduces real rates by raising inflationary expectations.

What about Global Aspects?

With the benefit of hindsight, I wish I had been clearer in seeking to resurrect the secular stagnation hypothesis that one should take a global perspective. Indeed, the lower level of rates, the greater tendency towards deflation, and inferior output performance in Europe and Japan suggests that the spectre of secular stagnation is greater for them than for the United States. Moreover, in a world with integrated capital markets real rates anywhere will depend on conditions everywhere. Particularly in the 2003-2007 period it is appropriate to regard Ben’s savings glut coming from abroad as an important impediment to demand in the United States. Ben and I are, I think, in agreement that it is important to think about the saving-investment balance not just for countries individually, but for the global economy. If there are more countries tending to have excess saving than there are tending towards excess investment, there will be a global shortage of demand. In this case countries able to devalue their currencies will benefit from generating more demand. Global mechanisms that concentrate on causing borrowing countries to adjust without seeking to shrink the surplus of surplus countries will tend to push the global economy towards contraction.
Successful policy approaches to a global tendency towards excess saving and stagnation will involve not only stimulating public and private investment but will also involve encouraging countries with excess saving to reduce their saving or increase their investment. Policies that seek to stimulate demand through exchange rate changes are a zero-sum game, as demand gained in one place will be lost in another. Secular stagnation and excess foreign saving are best seen alternative ways of describing the same phenomenon.

Final Thoughts

I would like nothing better than to be wrong as Alvin Hansen was with respect to secular stagnation. It may be that growth will soon take hold in the industrial world and allow interest rates and financial conditions to normalize. If so, those like Ben who judged slow recovery to be a reflection of temporary headwinds and misguided fiscal contractions will be vindicated and fears of secular stagnation will have been misplaced.
But throughout the industrial world the vast majority of the revisions in growth forecasts have been downwards for many years now. So, I continue to urge that it is worth taking seriously the possibility that we face a chronic problem of an excess of desired saving relative to investment. If this is the case, monetary policy will not be able to normalize, there will be a continuing need for expanded public and private investment, and there will be a need for global coordination to assure an adequate level of demand and its appropriate distribution. Macroeconomists can contribute by moving beyond their traditional models of business cycles to contemplate the possibility of secular stagnation.

Comments are now closed for this post.

Joe Oliver’s ‘balanced budget law’ is a political gimmick: Editorial

Joe Oliver’s ‘balanced budget law’ is a political gimmick: Editorial

The promise of a balanced budget law is nothing more than a political gesture designed to shore up the Harper government’s claims to fiscal conservatism.

At the Economic Club on April 8, 2015, Finance Minister Joe Oliver said he is planning to bring in a balanced budget law.
DARREN CALABRESE / THE CANADIAN PRESS
At the Economic Club on April 8, 2015, Finance Minister Joe Oliver said he is planning to bring in a balanced budget law.
Joe Oliver, the federal finance minister, must really take us all for fools. Speaking for a government that’s coming off a seven-year run of record budget deficits, adding up to a staggering total of $150 billion, Oliver now proposes to make balancing the budget the law of the land. This takes serious chutzpah.
Nonetheless, that’s what the minister promised Wednesday in a speech to Toronto’s Economic Club. The government, he said, plans to bring in legislation that would require Ottawa to balance its books — sort of.
Let’s be clear: this promise is nothing more than a political gesture designed to shore up the Harper government’s reputation among fiscal conservatives. After (quite understandably) running big deficits in response to the 2008-09 financial crisis, the government now wants to present itself to voters this fall as champions of old-tyme fiscal rectitude.
It won’t wash, for several reasons:

  • The law itself is bound to include so many qualifications and escape clauses that it will be basically meaningless.
  • On Wednesday, Oliver said the legislation will require the government to balance its books in “normal economic times” (whatever those are), but also permit it to run a deficit in the case of a recession or “extraordinary circumstances” such as war or natural disaster that costs more than $3 billion a year.
    These are loopholes big enough to allow the government to do pretty much what it wants. In other words, business as usual. Oliver’s proposed law would require a future government that goes into deficit to lay out “concrete timelines” for a return to balance and for ministers to suffer token 5-per-cent wage cuts if they fail. But the only real check would be, as usual, the vigilance of voters.

  • A quarter century of experience shows that “balanced budget” laws don’t work.
  • Such laws are nothing new in Canada. Since 1991, when British Columbia first brought in legislation along those lines, seven provinces (including Ontario under the Mike Harris government) have adopted some version.
    The pattern has been predictable. Governments usually bring in the laws in good times, when balancing the budget seems easy; they then ignore or repeal them when things get tough.
    A 2012 study by two University of Manitoba economists, Wayne Simpson and Jared Wesley, found that everywhere but in B.C. the growth in government spending actuallyincreased after balanced budget legislation was passed. The laws simply do not accomplish their stated goals, they found. Instead, “like every other piece of legislation, (balanced budget legislation) is only as strong as the political will and public support underlying it.”

  • Even if balanced budget legislation did work, it would be fundamentally wrong in that it aims to tie the hands of future elected governments.
  • Striking a balance between spending and saving is at the heart of our politics. That’s the biggest thing voters decide when they choose a new government. The Conservatives shouldn’t try, however ineptly, to impose their political agenda on future governments by constraining their ability to react to events.
    More broadly, the Conservatives’ drive for balanced budgets for the sake of balanced budgets ignores the overall balance in society. Oliver may well eliminate the deficit in his April 21 budget, but at what cost in terms of lost jobs, fraying social programs and eroding infrastructure?
    One of the biggest ironies in Oliver’s latest promise is that the Harper government itself is a case study in erasing budget surpluses, for both ideological and practical reasons.
    When the Conservatives were first elected in 2006, Ottawa had been running surpluses for years under Liberal prime ministers. The Conservatives immediately tossed away most of the surplus they inherited by slashing the GST by two percentage points, seriously undermining federal finances.
    Then when the Great Recession of 2008-09 hit they dumped their remaining deficit fears in the face of fierce criticism and opened the financial taps to make sure the crisis didn’t turn into a full-blown depression. In other words, they reacted as almost any government would — and will in the future, regardless of any budget laws.
    Oliver’s “balanced budget” law will be full of loopholes, ineffective and wrong on principle. Voters should see it for the election gimmick it is.

    Low rates will trigger unrest as central banks lose control - BIS


    Low rates will trigger unrest as central banks lose control - BIS

    Bank for International Settlements warns that low rates risk backlash as effects spill over into the real economy







    Low inflation, bond yields and interest rates around the world will push the boundaries of economic and political stability to breaking point if they continue on their downward trajectory, the Bank for International Settlements has warned
    Low interest rates have already led to gaping pension deficits and lower bank profits, while the returns on savers' deposits have been eroded by inflation Photo: Bloomberg News
    Low inflation, bond yields and interest rates around the world will push the boundaries of economic and political stability to breaking point if they continue on their downward trajectory, the Bank for International Settlements has warned.
    The Swiss-based "bank of central banks" said the "sinking trend" of global rates would push countries further into uncharted territory.
    It highlighted that $2.4 trillion (£1.6 trillion) of long-term global sovereign debt was now trading at negative yields, with an increasing number of investors willing to pay governments for the privilege of lending to them.
    "As bond markets show us day after day, the boundaries of the unthinkable are exceptionally elastic," said Claudio Borio, head of the Monetary and Economic department at the BIS.
    "The consequences should be watched closely, as the repercussions are bound to be significant."
    The BIS warned that the low rate environment risked creating instability.
    Low rates have already led to gaping pension deficits and lower bank profits, while the returns on savers' deposits have also been eroded.
    It said 20 central banks had eased monetary policy over the past three months alone. Mr Borio noted that the low rate environment had become so acute that even the International Monetary Fund had set a floor on its special drawing rights - which serves as the IMF's own form of international currency.
    "In such a world, easing begets easing," he said. "If this unprecedented journey continues, technical, economic, legal and even political boundaries may well be tested."
    Banks have been reluctant to pass on negative rates to retail depositors for fear of losing customers - even though it hurts their profit. JP Morgan said in February that it would start to charge large institutional clients to park their money at the bank.
    While low UK inflation, which stood at just 0.3pc in January, is expected to be temporary, Mark Carney, the governor of the Bank of England, said in a recent speech that interest rates could stay at a record low of 0.5pc for longer if the pound pushed inflation down further.
    Minouche Shafik, the Bank's deputy governor for banking and markets, outlined the risks of moving rates into negative territory in its most recent Inflation Report, and said that policymakers were watching developments in other countries closely.
    She said there was a risk that people and businesses could "revert to cash. [There is] also the worry about what happens to money markets when rates are negative," she said.
    Martin Weale, an external member of the Bank's Monetary Policy Committee that sets interest rates, said the bank contemplated using negative rates at the height of the eurozone debt crisis but decided against such a move because it would have signalled "a change in the nature of money as we know it". He said companies may have decided to hold money in secure warehouses instead of at the Bank if rates had been cut to below zero.
    However, Mr Carney has said capital rebuilding by banks has since reduced some of the risks associated with negative rates.
    A separate paper co-authored by Mr Borio argued that periods of deflation has less economic costs than sustained falls in property prices. Its analysis of 38 economies over a period of more than 100 years showed economies grew by an average of 3.2pc during deflationary periods, compared with 2.7pc when prices were rising.
    It said drawing blind comparisons with the 1930s were misguided. "The historical evidence suggests that the Great Depression was the exception rather than the rule," said Hyun Shin, head of research at the BIS.
    The Telegraph Investor
    Transfer your Isa's - buy & sell funds for free

    Damned if they Raise; Damned if they Don’t. The Dilemma Facing the US Central Bank - March 23, 2015 Stewart Richardson

    Damned if they Raise; Damned if they Don’t. The Dilemma Facing the US Central Bank

    Tall Office Buildings
    Stewart Richardson
    Renowned investors are becoming worried and credible institutions are becoming increasingly nervous about what impact interest rate rises could have the US equity market. From where we sit, we think that a phrase used by Marc Faber some months ago sums it up quite nicely (and we paraphrase here)…equity markets are going to fall a long way but it could be from a higher diving board.
    Before the financial crisis, the Bank for International Settlements (BIS – the bank for central banks) warned about financial instability, and remains one of the few institutions to have any real credibility. This past week, the BIS warned about the potentially extreme risks that come with zero or negative policy rates in most of the developed world. With more than 20 central banks easing policy further in recent weeks, the BIS warned… “In such a world, easing begets easing…If this unprecedented journey continues, technical, economic, legal and even political boundaries may well be tested.”(Please see the attached link to a Telegraph article about the BIS report). Clearly, the BIS thinks that interest rates have to rise at some point otherwise nasty and unexpected events may well occur.
    Within hours of the BIS report, Ray Dalio founder of Bridgewater (a US$165 billion hedge fund, so clearly a credible commentator) warned that the Fed risks causing a 1937 style market slump when it finally moves to raise interest rates. With the Dow Jones Industrials falling nearly 50% between March 1937 and March 1938, it seems like this warning should be taken seriously. Dalio went onto say that…“We don’t know — nor does the Fed know — exactly how much tightening will knock over the apple cart,…What we do hope the Fed knows, which we don’t know, is how exactly it will fix things if it knocks it over. We hope that they know that before they make a move that could knock over the apple cart.” See the link to an FT article for more colour on this.
    So, it appears that there is trouble ahead if central banks don’t raise rates, and there could be a whole lot of trouble if the Fed raises rates too much…and who knows (nobody including the Fed) what too much is. Furthermore, it is difficult to know what the Fed can do in the event of another bear market; except perhaps print more money – which an increasing number of commentators believe actually increases the risks of financial instability with very little real economic benefit.
    Where does this leave US equities? One of the simplest ways to illustrate current valuations is to revisit a metric that Warren Buffet explained in 2001 was his shorthand for valuing the market, namely the market value to GDP, illustrated in the chart below.
    As can be seen, aside from just a couple of quarters at the turn of the millennium (current comparison would place us somewhere in 2Q 1999), markets have not been this expensive since this particular data set started in 1951. Other analysts, splicing together this data with historic pre war data, can illustrate that the current market is the second most overvalued ever. The conclusion from this current level of valuation is that there is a bear market waiting out there somewhere (unless the Fed has abolished market cycles). The simple question is will the next bear market start in the next few weeks/months or perhaps 2016. Nobody knows, but the fundamental situation as highlighted by the views from the BIS and Ray Dalio is both unsustainable and increasingly fragile.
    We would add that a US equity bear market would most likely coincide with a global bear market with very few left unscathed. This is why we spend so much time analysing the US. Perhaps QE in some countries will make the bear market for them look a bit different, but we fully expect the upcoming bear market to be global in nature.
    From where we sit, the risk of an US economic growth shock continues to rise. Bloomberg has consensus expectations looking for 1Q growth of 2.4% and rising to basically 3% for the rest of the year. The Atlanta Fed GDPNow model we looked at last week is tracking 1Q growth of just 0.3% after last week’s updates. A recent BIS report claims that annual capex in the oil and gas sector doubled in real terms between 2000 and 2013 to US$900 billion. Estimates for reductions in capex for this sector are approaching 40% or approximately US$360 billion. This is about 2% of GDP alone and with oil reaching new lows this week, capex and jobs may well be cut further, with a reasonably high negative multiplier raising risk further.
    What is strange about the FOMC statement and Yellen’s press conference this week was that the bust in the energy sector was not even mentioned. The fallout from the collapse in energy prices is a positive for consumers of energy that may or may not spend their savings, but it is a macro disaster for capex and corporate profits which are leading indicators for the economy as we explained at the end of January.
    How can the Fed ignore such a massive macro event? Unemployment has fallen a lot but perhaps they also realise (just like the BIS) that holding rates at zero for 6 years and counting, and printing over US$3 trillion of new money, has massive unintended consequences. They realise that they need to try and raise rates sooner rather than later, and to be able to do so, they have to spin a narrative to the market that the economy is doing just fine. If this is the case, they have to paper over any obvious sign of weakness in the first quarter and continue to predict a solid pace of growth further out.
    Both the equity and bond markets have bought into this narrative, with equities up a lot in February and bonds down a lot. However, we think the odds of economic weakness from 1Q extending into 2Q are high, and the Fed may well not be able to raise rates at all. If this occurs, and the Fed has to further downgrade their forecasts and admit they cannot raise rates, bond and equity investors will question the Fed’s credibility and will have to adjust their own forecasts for growth and earnings. This loss in the Fed’s credibility will be obviously bullish for high quality bonds, and may prove enough to pop the equity bubble.
    - See more at: http://www.marketviews.com/damned-raise-damned-dont-dilemma-facing-us-central-bank/#sthash.61ofbwc6.dpuf

    Oil prices dropped on Wednesday after Saudi Arabia reported record production

    SINGAPORE (Reuters) - Crude prices dropped on Wednesday after Saudi Arabia reported record production of 10.3 million barrels per day in March, a figure the country's oil minister said was unlikely to fall by much.
    The decline in prices followed a rally on Tuesday in which U.S. crude approached 2015 highs on strong jobs data, as well as government forecasts for lower U.S. crude production growth and higher global demand for oil.
    Saudi oil minister Ali al-Naimi told reporters late on Tuesday that the March figure of 10.3 million barrels per day (bpd) would eclipse its recent peak of 10.2 million bpd in August 2013, according to records going back to the early 1980s.
    Brent May crude was down 73 cents from its last settlement at $58.37 a barrel by 0100 GMT, while U.S. May crude fell over a dollar to $52.96 a barrel. Both futures have dropped around 50 percent since June last year, when prices began to fall.
    Naimi did not say why production had increased last month. He said in the speech in Riyadh that Saudi output would likely remain around 10 million bpd.
    Ali al-Naimi also said that the kingdom stood ready to "improve" prices but only if other producers outside the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) joined the effort.
    The U.S. dollar index, which measures the greenback against a basket of currencies, rose 1.22 percent on Tuesday, resuming a recent upward trend and weighing on crude prices.
    Meanwhile, Royal Dutch Shell is in advanced talks to buy BG Group in the first oil super-merger since the early 2000s to extend its global lead in gas production and close the gap with the world's biggest independent oil major ExxonMobil.
    (Editing by Joseph Radford)

    Templeton's Mark Mobius: Chinese stocks face 20% drop after rising too fast

    Templeton's Mark Mobius: Chinese stocks face 20% drop after rising too fast

    ChineseFactory
    Tags: China
    Mark Mobius says Chinese stocks have risen too fast after a world-beating rally sent the benchmark equity gauge to its highest level in seven years.
    A 20 percent retreat is “very possible,” Mobius, who oversees about $40 billion as the executive chairman of Templeton Emerging Markets Group, told reporters in Hong Kong. The Shanghai Composite Index rallied 90 percent in the past 12 months, the most among 92 global benchmark measures tracked by Bloomberg.
    While Mobius says the bull market in Chinese stocks is “intact,” he’s turning cautious in the short term after investors opened a record number of new stock accounts and increased margin debt to all-time highs. Mainland shares are unlikely to gain entry into MSCI Inc. indexes this year, limiting demand from international investors, he said.
    “It has gone a little too far and too fast,” Mobius said.
    Chinese investors opened a record 1.7 million accounts to trade equities in the week to March 27, while there is now more than 1 trillion yuan ($161 billion US) of borrowed cash riding on the stock market.
    In a margin trade, investors use their own money for just a portion of their stock purchase, borrowing the rest from a brokerage. The loans are backed by the investors’ equity holdings, meaning that they may be compelled to sell when prices fall to repay their debt. The Shanghai Composite rose 0.8 percent at close at 3,994.81 after briefly surpassing 4,000.
    Custodian Risk
    “Too much credit is not a good thing in the long run,” Mobius said. “When the market turns, it could be a problem.”
    He’s avoiding buying mainland shares through the Hong Kong trading link due to “restrictive” rules on share ownership.
    “According to Chinese regulations, the titles pass to the custodians in China and our custodian banks refuse to allow that,” Mobius said. “That’s a problem. I don’t see how this can be resolved. The Shanghai connect won’t work unless they revise regulations to allow foreign custodians to keep possession.”
    Foreign funds sold a net 2.2 billion yuan ($460 million US) of mainland equities through the Hong Kong trading link today, poised for the most on record.
    China is the biggest weighting in his Asian funds, followed by India and Thailand. Mobius said he favours banks on the outlook for financial reforms as well as auto and technology stocks for their growth prospects.
    Bull Market
    “The bull market is still intact,” he said. “It can go for five years to 10 years.”
    The ultimate inclusion of Chinese shares in MSCI global benchmarks together with the nation’s capital-market liberalization will provide the market with incentives to climb further in the long run, he said.
    Templeton also favours Vietnam and Nigeria among frontier markets because of their valuations and growth potential. Mobius said he recently bought some Macau casino stocks, while he’s waiting for a correction in Indian shares before increasing holdings there.

    728 X 90

    336 x 280

    300 X 250

    320 X 100

    300 X600